Friday, 23 August 2013

Foreign Remittances, Income Inequality and Non-Linearity: Evidence from Pakistan by Muhammad Shahbaz

Abstract: This paper explains large empirical literature and demonstrates evidence on the relationship between foreign remittances and distribution of income. Using time series data covering period 1971-2006 and three advanced techniques [Johansen Trace-Test, DOLS Method and ARDL Bounds Testing] model for co-integration, we found robust evidence of long run relationship among the said variables. In the case of Pakistan, the relationship between foreign remittances and income inequality is U-shaped indicating that inequality initially decreases and then increases as emigration continues. Our empirical findings support the evidence that foreign remittances has income distribution worsening impact in the long run while local migration (rural-urban) declines income inequality. Increase in per capita income pushes income inequality to upward direction, which means, inequality is encouraged by an increase in per capita income. Improvements in human capital formation worsen the situation of income distribution.  Inflation lowers the purchasing power of poor individuals in the economy and raises inequality through its detrimental channels like wise unemployment. Increase in government consumption worsens the income inequality, which indicates that rich households use their political powers to exploit the poor, which raises the income inequality swiftly. This unique endeavor presents some policy implications for policy makers in a small developing country like Pakistan.

Keywords: Migration, Foreign Remittances, Income Inequality
JEL Classification: O11, O15, D31 

1.      Introduction

Remittances inflows are a key and stable source of foreign capital and revenue in developing economies because there is no need to depend on external factors like foreign loans and aids etc.[1] In literature, the relationship between foreign migrants’ remittances and income inequality is scarce and incongruous. Some empirical evidences showed that remittances worsens the income distribution (Milanovic, 1987; Stark et  al., 1988, Taylor, 1992; Taylor and Wyatt, 1996; Adams, 1989; Rodriguez, 1998; Leones and Feldman, 1998; Adger, 1999; Gonzalez-Konig and Wodon, 2005). In contrast, other argued that foreign remittances decrease the income inequality (Barham and Stepehn, 1998; Ahlburg, 1996; Handa and King, 1997), but Adams (1992) found no significant impact of remittances on rural income distribution in case of Pakistan.[2]

In the late 1980s, Lipton in his pioneer work viewed that migrants’ remittances generate negative externalities of various types and these externalities are responsible for an increase in income inequality. He also described that remittances do not reimburse for said undesirable impact because the migrants’ remittances are either very small or go disproportionately to those better off. In contrast, Stark (1978) and Stark et al. (1986) in their models, emphasized on equality-enhancing consideration associated with migration such as risk-diversification, mitigation of credit constraints and various sharing and filtering-down mechanisms pertaining to migrants remittances.[3] They also concluded that income inequality does not mean a social welfare loss, and may be consistent with situation that is preferred under both general social welfare and Pereto criteria.[4] Stark et al. (1988) distinguished that the distributional impacts of migration are not the same for all types of migration and concluded that foreign remittances contribute in raising income inequality while internal remittances are having equalizing favorable impact on village income distribution.[5]

Stark et al. (1986) found the relationship between foreign remittances and income inequality is an inverse U-shaped (Kuznets Curve). It means that initially un-equalizing effects of remittances on income distribution of a village decreases at latter stages of the village’s migration history. Jones (1998) distinguished three stages of migration: first is the “innovative stage” in which only the most adventurous and better off people migrate, in that case international remittances tend to increase income inequality; second is the early adopter stage”, when people from lower segments of population also start to migrate and comparatively, remittances become more equalizing the income distribution; and lastly, the “latter adopter stage”, when due to accumulation over time of remittances in the families with migrants, those families move farther apart from the families without migrants and therefore remittances may be worsening the income distribution. Stark et al.(1986) found that, in a Mexican village with little migration to United-States, remittances are contributing in inequality to rise while opposite is true for village where migration to United-States has long migration history.[6] But, Konig and Wodon (2005) extended the mythology developed by Yitzhaki (1982) and Stark et al. (1986) and accomplished that impact of remittances on inequality depends where those who migrate are located in the distribution of income.

Lermann and Yitzhaki (1998) concluded that remittances income distributes more to the Gini-Coefficient than its share of total income indicates and it tends to increase inequality in the community utilizing the Gini-Coefficient decomposition method. Carrington et al. (1996) found that international remittances are likely to have different impact at different levels of a villages’ migration history while net migration cost becomes endogenous to migration process.[7] Similarly, Quibria (1997) argued that foreign remittances do not affect all the classes in the society symmetrically utilizing the two-factor, two-commodity, two-class general equilibrium model that makes a distinction between traded and non-traded goods.[8] The division of losers and gainers depends on the volume of remittances, the distribution of factors of endowments and type of emigration.[9]

Taylor (1992) utilized technique for the estimation of direct, indirect and inter-temporal special effects of foreign remittances on the distribution income and confirmed that remittances have indirect short run and long run asset accumulation impacts on the level and distribution of household-farm income. In long run, remittances may finance the accumulation of income-producing assets on household farms. By influencing the distribution of these assets, remittances may help to reshape the distribution of total household-farm income overtime (Taylor, 1992; Rodriguez, 1998; Leones and Feldman, 1998). Lucas (1987) found a positive link between migrant remittances and agricultural productivity. Milanovic (1987) in the case of Yugoslavia tested for the possibility of trickle-down effect and found no support for the hypothesis: remittances increase income inequality throughout the period, and so, more for the farm-households. Due to the existence of imperfection of local credit or labor markets; migrant remittances encourage the household to utilize such inputs, which are associated with higher crop incomes. The marginal impact of remittances on household farm incomes thus may be greater than unitary (Oberai and Singh, 1980; Knowles and Anker, 1981; Stark, 1982; Lucas, 1987 and Taylor, 1992). On the basis of deprivation theory; Gonzalez-Konig and Wodon (2005) came to conclusion that in poor and rural areas where level of social welfare tends to be lower, part of the expected positive impact of foreign remittances on family income might be offset by a higher level of income inequality at home. However at the margin, remittances are less likely to improve the income distribution in poorer (rural) as compared to richer (urban) areas.[10]

Koechlin and Leon (2006) provided the evidence in the support of existing theoretical literature that accounts for the network effects that, the initial stages of migration history generates inequality-worsening impact of remittances. Then as opportunity cost of migration lowers, remittances sent to those households reduce income inequality: a clear indication of inverted U-shaped relationship between remittances and income inequality.[11] David and Rapoport (2004) investigated the overall impact of migration on distribution of income in Mexican rural communities. This impact is composed of direct and indirect effects of remittances, and other potential spillover and general equilibrium effects of migration. They found that migration ability with their accords raise expected benefits and decease the costs of migration, and generate a Kuznets-type relationship between remittances and income inequality.[12] All these studies based on the Gini-Index decomposition with exogenous distribution of domestic incomes may yield biased estimates of the inequality impact of international remittances, with the direction of bias being theoretically uncertain and depending on the initial distribution of wealth.  Gini-Index decomposition only provides information about point that decomposed.

Despite the fact, that a wide rage of strand of economic research has investigated the effects of remittances on variety of topics along-with employing variety of techniques with different aspects. There is no formal study to analyze either remittances improve income distribution or worsen in the case of Pakistan utilizing large time series data. One may say that this small effort is advancement over previous literature in a number of important aspects. First, it uses the data set that is sufficiently large to enable robust conclusions to be drawn from econometric results; specifying the sample utilized in this paper consists of annual data covering the period 1971-2006.  Second, this paper includes other important determents, to investigate their impacts on income inequality like government spending, human capital formation, financial development, unemployment rate and local migration (urbanization) which are ignored in all previous literature.[13]  Third, this paper employs three advance techniques (Johansson Trace-Test, DOLS, Dynamic Ordinary Least Squares and ARDL Bounds Testing) for co-integration and robustness of long run relationships among variables while Error Correction Method (ECM) for short run dynamics.[14] Section 2 explains the model, data collection procedure and methodological framework; Section 3 investigates and interprets empirical results. Finally, Section 4 presents the conclusions and also provides some policy implications.

2.  Modeling, Data and Methodology

According to assumptions of Barro (1991) and Koechlin and Leon (2006), the most important econometric classification to investigate the significant relationship between income inequality and foreign remittances; we utilize log-linear modeling specification as given below. Bowers and Pierce (1975) suggest that Ehrlich’s (1975) findings with a log linear specification are sensitive to functional form. However, Ehrlich (1977) and Layson (1983) argue on theoretical and empirical grounds that the log linear form is superior to the linear form. Both Cameron (1994) and Ehrlich (1996) suggest that a log-linear form is more likely to find evidence of a deterrent effect than a linear form. This makes our results more favorable to the deterrence hypothesis. Following the above discussion empirical equation is being modeled as:

                       (1)

(2)


The inequality-narrowing hypothesis predicts <0, in contrast the inequality-widening hypothesis predicts >0 and, inverted U-shaped hypothesis predicts if >0 and <0, if <0 and >0 U-shaped hypothesis predicts and CV are some control variables that effect income inequality.

Where Gini is measure of income inequality proxied by Gini-coefficient while REM is a measure of international remittances, expecting declining impact on income inequality as described in literature but may be positive through its detrimental channels.[15] Real GDP per capita (GDPPC) is assuming inverse impact through its development process. HDI represents the human capital formation, which may be affecting income inequality either positively or negatively.  CPI indicates the inflationary situation in the economy and assuming that, monetary instability hurts poor and middle class relatively more than rich because latter class has better access to financial instruments that allow them to hedge their exposure to inflation and expecting positive effect of inflation on inequality[16]; while measure of government general consumption expenditures conjecturing negative effect on inequality, but there can be opposite effect of government consumption on inequality if rich households use their political powers to exploit the poor.[17] Urbanization is represented by URB which might decline the income inequality through the creation of employment opportunities.[18] Unemployment rate worsens distribution of income through its direct and detrimental impacts, indicated by UMP. FD is measure of financial sector’s development proxied by Credit to private as share of GDP may equalizes the income distribution directly and indirectly through growth sound effects.[19]

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics and Correlation Matrix
Variables
GINI
GS
HDI
REM
CPI
GDPPC
Observations
36
36
36
36
36
36
Mean
3.599
26.108
-0.825
1.223
3.961
9.484
Median
3.612
26.336
-0.804
1.565
3.950
9.496
Maximum
3.758
27.000
-0.616
2.360
5.101
10.200
Minimum
3.413
25.150
-1.108
-2.338
1.950
8.950
 Std. Dev.
0.106
0.549
0.151
1.008
0.890
0.340
 Skew-ness
-0.252
-0.308
-0.271
-1.546
-0.471
0.309
 Kurtosis
1.843
1.753
1.790
5.639
2.418
2.372
 Jarque-Bera
2.389
2.901
2.637
24.806
1.843
1.166
 Probability
0.302
0.234
0.267
0.0000
0.397
0.558
 Sum
129.59
939.91
29.732
44.035
142.62
341.42
 Sum Sq.Dev.
0.394
10.571
0.806
35.580
27.732
4.059
GINI
1





GS
0.9744
1




HDI
0.997
0.973
1



REM
0.348
0.340
0.328
1


CPI
0.983
0.937
0.985
0.396
1

GDPPC
0.925
0.912
0.912
0.163
0.854
1
Source: Author’s own calculations.

Descriptive statistics in Table 1 reveals that government spending, human capital formation, consumer prices and GDP per capita are highly but remittances are weakly correlated with income inequality. Human capital formation, consumer prices and economy size are associated with government spending positively but correlation of remittances is weak as mentioned in descriptive table. The data has been collected from IFS (International Financial Statistics, 2007), WDI (World Development Indicators, 2007) and Economic Survey of Pakistan (Various Issues) except income inequality.[20]

2.2 KPSS Unit Root Test

Literature reveals that ADF and P-P test are having low explaining power especially in small sample data set. Shift has been focused to KPSS (1992)[21] to investigate the order of integration for concerned actors in the model. KPSS (1992) test assumes null hypothesis is stationary and vice versa. KPPS test states that any time series variable like  is the combination of three mechanisms i.e. deterministic trend, random walk plus error term as given below:

                                                     (3)                   

In Equation (4), random walk is specified as following:
                                                                     (4)

To check out the stationarity of,  is regressed on constant and trend terms, residuals from equation are used finally i.e.  for statistics of KPSS test:
                                                                     (5)
where

and. In KPSS test

Bartlett wind is utilized which is assumed, main reason is that KPSS test is highly sensitive with change of truncation lags.

2.3 Johansen Co-integration Technique

Engle and Granger (1987) discussed that, a set of economic series is not stationary, there may have to exist some linear combination of the variables that is stationary. Now, when all the variables are non-stationary at their level but stationary in their 1st difference, this allows proceeding further for the implementation of Johansen co-integration technique (1991; 1995). Economically speaking, two variables will be co-integrated if they have a long-term relationship between them. Thus, co-integration of two series suggests that there is a long integration tests and of course, the system approach developed by Johansen (1991,1995) can also applied to a set of variables containing possibly a mixture of I(0) and I(1) (Pesaran and Smith (1998) and Pesaran et al. (1997). The general form of the vector error correction model is as follows:


This can also be written in standard form as:

                       (6)

where

 and

where p is represents total number of variables considered in the model. The matrixcaptures the long run relationship between the p-variables. Now for the Johansson Test we employ the Trace test, which is based on the evaluation of  against the null hypothesis of, where r indicates number of co-integrating vectors. The co-integration test provides an analytical statistical framework for investigating the long run relationship between economic variables in the model.

2.3 DOLS Procedure for Long Run Relationship

Stock and Watson (1993) developed a model for the investigation of long run relationships among dependent variable and explanatory variables. This procedure involves regressing the dependent variable on all explanatory variables in levels, leads and  lags of the first difference of all I(1) explanatory variables (Masih and Masih, 1996). This method is superior to a number of other estimators as it can be applied to systems of variables with different orders of Integration (Stock and Watson, 1993). The inclusion of leads and lags of the differenced explanatory variables corrects for simultaneity bias and small sample bias among the regressors (Stock and Watson, 1993). The specification of DOLS model is follows given below:

                  (7)

where Xt is Gini-Coefficient, Zt is a vector of explanatory variables and D is lag operator.

2.4 ARDL Approach for Co-Integration

The structure of the study has suggested to employ autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) bounds testing approach developed by Pesaran et al. (2001) to carry out co-integration analysis among income inequality and international remittances with battery of other explanatory variables. Statistical literature reveals that ARDL bounds approach has numerous advantages than other conventional co-integrating methods. In ARDL technique, there is no need of having same order of integration to find out co-integration among macroeconomic variables. It is concluded that ARDL can be applied irrespectively of whether the variable are integrated of order I(0) or integrated of order I(1)[22] or having mixed order of integration. Fortunately, ARDL bounds testing overcomes all problems faced by traditional techniques for co-integration in literature. It has better explaining power and properties such small sample data. Moreover, a dynamic error correction model (ECM) can be derived from ARDL through a simple linear transformation (Banerrjee et al., 1993). The dynamic ECM integrates the short-run dynamics with the long-run equilibrium without losing long-run information.

Conditional error correction version of the ARDL model for co-integration is given below:

         (8)

where  is the drift component and  is assumed to be white noise error process. The ARDL approach estimate number of regression in order to obtain optimal lag length for each variable, where ‘p’ is the maximum number of lag to be used and “k” is the number of variable in the equation (1). The optimal lag order of the first difference regression is based on minimum value of Schwarz-Bayesian criteria (SBC) to ensure that there is no serial correlation in the estimated residual[23] of equation. Following Pesaran et al. (2001), two different statistics are implemented to “bound test” for ensuring of long-run relationship: an F-test for the joint significant of the coefficients of the lagged levels in Eq. (8) (with null hypothesis means no evidence of existence of long run relationship in concerned model and vice versa. Two asymptotic critical value bounds provide a test for co-integration when the independent variables are I(d)  ( Where 0 ≤ d ≤ 1), a lower value assuming the regressors are I(0), and an upper value assuming purely I(1) regressors. If the F-statistics exceeds the upper critical value, we can conclude that there prevails a long run relationship regardless of whether the underlying order of integration of the variables is I(0) or I(1). If the F-statistics falls below the lower critical values one cannot reject the null hypothesis of no co-integration. If the F-statistics exceeds the upper bounds, one may reject the hypotheses of no long run relationship. However, if the F-statistics falls between these two bounds, inference would be inconclusive.[24] If any variable is having I(2) integrating order, then ARDL bounds testing will be collapsed.

Then, the long-run connection is investigated through use of selected ARDL model. If variables are co-integrated, the conditional long run model can then be produced from the reduced form of Eq. (8), when the first differenced variables jointly equal to zero, i.e. . Thus,

                (9)


where    , and are the random errors. These long run coefficients are empirically estimated by the ARDL, model in Equation (1) through OLS method. When   there is long relationship between variables, there also exists error correction representation. Therefore, the error correction model is estimated generally as in the following given reduced form:                                              

     (10)

To ascertain the goodness of fit of the ECM model, the sensitivity analysis is conducted. The diagnostic test examines the serial correlation, functional form, normality and heteroskedasticity associated with the model. The stability test is conducted by employing the cumulative sum of recursive residuals (CUSUM) and the cumulative sum of squares of recursive residuals (CUSUMsq). Examining the prediction error of the model is another way of ascertaining the reliability of the ARDL model. If the error or the difference between the real observation and the forecast is infinitesimal, then the model can be regarded as best fitting.


3. Interpretation Design

Prior step to investigate the order of integration of individual series; ADF (Augmented Dickey-Fuller) Phillips-Perron and KPSS tests have been utilized in the present study. Results of both tests are reported in Table 2; all variables are stationary at their 1st difference form through employing ADF, P-P and KPSS tests.[25] Results of latter test also prove that all the series are trend stationary.



Table 2: Unit-Root Estimation

Variables
ADF Test at 1st Difference
Phillips-Perron at 1st Difference
KPSS at 1st Difference
Intercept and trend
Prob.
Values
Lags

Intercept and trend
Prob.
Values
Bandwidth
Intercept and trend
Bandwidth
LGINI
-3.945
0.021
2
-3.477
 0.0580
10
 0.1432**
9
LREM
-9.048
0.000
0
-7.765
 0.0000
4
0.1087***
3
LGS
-3.564
0.048
1
-6.626
0.000
3
0.0996***
1
LGDPC
-5.420
0.000
0
-5.240
0.0009
3
0.1064***
4
LHDI
-3.244
0.094
3
-16.145
0.000
4
0.0852***
5
LCPI
-5.104
0.001
0
-5.281
0.0007
2
0.1236**
1
Lag Length Selection of VAR Model
Lags
AIC
SBC
Maximum Likelihood
1
-22.95081
-21.08439
443.6392
2
-26.87495
-23.37330
534.8742
Note: ** and *** are MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values at 5 percent and 10 percent level of confidence, respectively.



This tends to support for the employment of the most advanced techniques for the investigation of long run relationships among the macroeconomic variables. Lag length of VAR model is selected 2 on the basis of (AIC) and (SBC). After having information about order of integration of all series and before going to ARDL, Johansen Co-integration test is applied and results are shown in Table 3. Starting with the null hypothesis of no Co-integration () among the variables, the trace-test statistics is 236.1014, which is above 1 percent and 5 percent critical values as shown by the Prob-value. Hence it rejects null hypothesis in the favor of general alternative. Likewise null hypothesis of no Co-integration () among the variables, the trace-test statistics is 142.0879, which is above 1 percent and 5 percent critical values as shown by the Prob-value. So, it also rejects null hypothesis in the favor of general alternative. Consequently, one may conclude that there are six Co-integrating relationships among income inequality, remittances as share of GDP, human capital formation, GDP per capita, government spending and consumer prices.

Table 3: Johansen’s Multiple Co-integration Test Results

Hypotheses
Trace-Test
0.05 percent critical value
Prob.**
R = 0
 236.1014
 117.7082
 0.000
R £ 1
 142.0879
 88.80380
 0.000
R £ 2
 91.02466
 63.87610
 0.000
R £ 3
 46.72793
 42.91525
 0.019
R £ 4
 27.35478
 25.87211
 0.033
R £ 5
 12.66226
 12.51798
 0.047
Note: **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values

Therefore, over annual data from 1971 to 2006 appears to support the proposition that in Pakistan; there does exist a stable long-run relationship among above-mentioned variables in the model. The results of DOLS (Dynamic Ordinary Least Square) are reported in Appendix-A; only significant regressors are shown in the Table 7. Adjusted-R2   value of 0.999692 is an indication of good-fit for the dataset, the F-statistics-10714.32 (Prob-value = 0.00) is statistically significant at 1 percent level of significance, concluding that the explanatory variables are jointly significant in influencing distribution of income for a small developing economy like Pakistan. The results of DOLS regression show that in long run international remittances, human capital formation and increase in per capita income along with inflation and government spending are having positive impact on income inequality, however, leads of inflation and human capital formation. Finally, differenced terms of government spending, remittances and GDP per capita improve distribution of income (Appendix-A).

Finally, ARDL for long run relationships is also applied and results are expressed in Table 4. The main assumption of ARDL is that the included variables in model are having co-integrated order I(0) or I(1) or mutually. This tends to support for the implementation of bounds testing, which is tree step procedure, in the first step we selected lag order on the basis of SBC because computation of F-statistics for Co-integration is very much sensitive with lag length, so lag order 2 is selected on lowest value of SBC[26]. The total number of regressions estimated following the ARDL method in the Equation 2 is 729.

Table 4: F-statistic of Co-integration Relationship

Test-statistic
Calculated Value

Lag-order

Significance level
Bound Critical Values(restricted intercept and no trend)
F-statistic


9.17
2

1 percent
5 percent
10 percent
I(0)
I(1)
5.25
3.79
3.17
6.36
4.85
4.14
Short Run Diagnostic Tests
Serial Correlation LM Test =0.195(0.824)
ARCH Test = 0.196(0.664)
White Heteroskedasticity Test = 1.721(0.138)
Normality J-B Value = 1.998(0.368)
Ramsey RESET Test = 10.255(0.0038)
Source: Author’s own calculations.

Given the existence of a long run relationship, in the next we used the ARDL co-integration method to estimate the parameters of log-linear Equation (1) with a maximum order of lag set to 2 minimize the loss of degrees of freedom. The results of bounds testing approach for long run relationship represent that; calculated F-statistic is 9.17, which is higher than the upper bound (6.36) and lower bound (5.25) at 1 percent level of significance, implying that the null hypothesis of no co-integration cannot be accepted and, indicating that there is indeed a co-integration relationship among the variables as long-established by J-J maximum likelihood approach..

Long-run coefficients of the variables under investigation are shown in the Table 5. Model 1 reveals that increase in remittances seems to worsen the income distribution significantly. The reason for this is that increase in cost of migration pushes the poor segments of population downward and rich are obtaining the fruits of migration and getting richer and richer, while rapid increase in per capita income also pushes the income inequality upward because growth effects did not trickle down to lowest quintile of population (bottom 20 percent) according upper-echelon phenomenon in the country. Low down income inequality is coupled with low rate of human capital formation. Consumer prices rise makes income distribution more skewed through its detrimental direct and indirect channels[27]. Government spending affects the income inequality positively and significantly because rich households use their political powers to exploit the poor, which worsens the income distribution swiftly. There is also evidence of an increase in income inequality as international migration history continues, means, relationship between remittances and income inequality is Kuznets inverted U-shaped. This shows another proof of linear association between foreign remittances and income distribution, while internal migration (rural-urban) makes income distribution more equal through obtaining fruits from employment opportunities in urban areas.[28] Combined impact of remittances and human capital formation on income inequality is negative which indicates that improvements in human capital formation through remittances equate the distribution of income.        

Table 5: Long Run OLS (Ordinary Least Squares) Results

Dependent Variable: LGINI
Variable
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
Model 5
Constant
2.741***
(7.77)
3.164***
(9.17)
2.729***
(6.90)
2.717***
(6.98)
2.698***
(6.81)
LREM
0.003**
(2.41)
0.002**
(2.34)
-0.0179*
(-1.70)
-0.0157
(-1.47)
-0.0374
(-0.93)
LREM2
…….
…….
0.0013*
(1.90)
0.0008
(1.03)
0.0007
(1.01)
LGDPC
0.052**
(6.87)
0.053***
(7.75)
0.059***
(6.93)
0.055***
(6.05)
0.055***
(6.00)
LHDI
0.325***
(3.71)
0.327***
(4.19)
0.275***
(3.52)
0.272***
(3.49)
0.274***
(3.47)
LCPI
0.033*** (3.41)
0.032***
(3.79)
0.038***
(4.38)
0.034***
(3.69)
0.033***
(3.49)
LGS
0.019** (2.104)
0.006
(0.62)
0.016*
(1.65)
0.018*
(1.81)
0.020*
(1.87)
LURB
…….
-0.058***
(-2.96)
-0.047**
(-2.42)
-0.046**
(-2.45)
-0.044**
(-2.20)
LEMP
…….
…….
…….
0.009*
(1.71)
0.010*
(1.76)
LFD
…….
…….
…….
0.003
(0.26)
-0.003
(-0.20)
LREM*LHDI
…….
…….
-0.019*
(-1.82)
-0.017
(-1.57)
-0.021
(-1.58)
LREM*LFD
…….
…….
…….
…….
0.005
(0.56)
= 0.998294
Durban-Watson = 1.74
F-stat = 3510.42
= 0.998690
Durban-Watson = 1.71
F-stat = 3685.73
= 0.998889
Durban-Watson = 1.76
F-stat = 3034.93
= 0.999005
Durban-Watson = 1.97
F-stat = 2510.68
= 0.999018
Durban-Watson = 1.94
F-stat = 2220.263
  Note: ***, ** and * represent 1 percent, 5 percent and 10 percent level of significance, respectively.

Inequality is being positively affected by an increase in unemployment level, while access to credit (financial development) seems to worsen the income distribution insignificantly due to low quality and efficiency of financial institutions.[29] Combined impact of remittances and financial development is positive but insignificant describing that remittances are increasing inequality because these are not properly channelizing through banking sector due to low incentive to migrants. Net effect of financial sector’s development improves distribution of income insignificantly.

Having found a long run relationship, we applied the ARDL method to investigate the long run but for short run estimation, we followed the Equation 1 and utilized the below given model for short run dynamics.

   (11)



Table 6: Short-Run Dynamic Model (1, 1, 2, 2, 1, 1)

Dependent Variable: DLIGNI
Variable
Coefficient
Prob-value
Constant
0.0041
0.1056
DLREM
-0.0008
0.6806
DLGDPC
0.0550
0.0030
DLGDPC(-1)
-0.0087
0.5851
DLCPI
0.0347
0.0458
DLCPI(-1)
-0.0023
0.8811
DLHDI
0.0602
0.4485
DLGS
0.0143
0.1040
CR(-1)
-0.6043
0.0218
= 0.542                                   -Adjusted =0.395
Durban-Watson = 1.74                F-stat = 3.69(0.005)
Source: Author’s own calculations.

Following the above ECM equation, results are reported in Table 6. The results indicate that, remittances improve the income distribution in short run insignificantly but increase in the volume of per capita income worsens the income distribution. Lag impact of GDP per capita declines the income inequality but insignificantly, and this effect converges to its future affect. Consumer prices rise and enhancement in government spending increase income inequality. Finally, human capital improvement pushes income distribution to skew insignificantly.

The error correction term CRt-1, which measures the speed of adjustment to restore equilibrium in the dynamics model, appear with negative sign and is statistically significant at 5 percent level, ensuring that long run equilibrium can be attained. Bannerjee and Newman (1993) holds that a highly significant error correction term is a further proof of the existence of stable long run relationship.[30] The coefficient of CR(-1) is equal to (-0.604) for short run model respectively and imply that deviation from the long-term income inequality is corrected by (0.604) percent over the each year. The lag length of short run model is selected on the basis of AIC and SBC. The short run dynamics of the income inequality based on ARDL (1, 1, 2, 2, 1, 1) model for Pakistan is reported in Table 4. The diagnostic statistics indicate that the equation is mis-specified. The model fulfilled the conditions of non-serial correlation, no autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity and normality of disturbance term. There is no heteroskedasticity in the short model.

Finally, we examine the stability of the long run parameters together with the short run movements for the equation. To this end, we rely on cumulative sum (CUSUM) and cumulative sum squares (CUSUMSQ) tests proposed by Borensztein et al. (1995; 1998). The same procedure has been used by Pesaran and Pesaran (1997) to test the stability of the long run coefficients. The tests applied to the residuals of the ECM model (Table 2) along with the critical bounds are graphed in Figures 1. As can be seen in the figures, the plot of CUSUM stay within the critical 5 percent bounds for all equations but and CUSUMsq statistics exceeds the critical boundaries due to misspecification of short run model.

4. Conclusions and Policy Implications

Present paper explains large empirical literature and explores empirical evidence on the relationship between international remittances and distribution of income. Using large time series data covering period 1971-2006 and three advanced techniques Johansen Trace-test, DOLS and ARDL model for co-integration, we found robust evidence of long run relationship among the said variables. In the case of Pakistan, the relationship between international remittances and income inequality is U-shaped indicating that inequality initially decreases and then increases as migration history continues.

Our empirical findings support the evidence that international remittances increases inequality in the long run while local migration improves income distribution. Increase in per capita income pushes the income inequality upwards means inequality is encouraged by an increase in per capita income. Improvements in human capital formation worsen the situation of income distribution. Inflation lowers the purchasing power of poor individuals in the economy and raises inequality through its detrimental channels like unemployment. Increase in government consumption worsens the income inequality, which indicates that rich households use their political powers to exploit the poor, which raises the income inequality swiftly.

The main policy implication of this study is that while encouraging migration, it may increase the economic development in less developed areas or region of the country, which will improve the income distribution and alleviate poverty. A higher development in financial institutions and markets will allow an easier and cheaper transmission of migrants’ remittances; lower transaction cost will also allow poorer households to receive remittances at earlier stages of migration, compared to how long they would have to wait if financial markets are less developed. Therefore, financial sector should regulate its institutions and markets to launch such policies to provide some particular incentives for remittance senders through proper formal banking system. Government should adopt such policies to enhance the volume of skilled labor through technical education at rural areas. More opportunities could be enhanced through regulation of recruitment process and safe transport facilities through supporting working rights for poor class. There will be a need to take initiatives to promote transport and safe mechanism for migrants to send small sums of money, and to create a more attractive investment climate in the country particularly in rural areas to alleviate poverty from its roots. More migrants’ remittances from abroad mean more national saving which is pre-requisites for development process and economic growth.












References

Adams, R. 1989. “Workers remittances and inequality in rural EgyptEconomic Development and Cultural Change 38 (1): 45-71.

Adams, R. 1992. “The impact of migration and remittances on inequality in rural PakistanPakistan Development Review 31(4): 1189-203.

Adger, W. N. 1999. “Exploring income inequality in rural, coastal Viet NamJournal of Development Studies 35(5): 96–119.

Ahlburg, D. A. 1996. “Remittances and the income distribution in TongaPopulation Research and Policy Review 15(4): 391–400.

Bahmani-Oskooee, M. and R. Ng 2002. “Long run demand for money in Hong Kong: an application of the ARDL model” International journal of Business and Economics 1(2): 147-155.

Banerjee, A. and A. Newman 1993. "Occupational choice and the process of development." Journal of Political Economy 101(21): 274-298. 

Barham, B. and B. Stephen 1998. “Migration, remittances, and inequality: estimating the net effects of migration on income distribution” Journal of Development Economics 55(2): 307–31.

Barro, R. 1991. “Economic growth in a cross-section of countries” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(2): 407-444.

Borensztein, E., J. Gregorio and J. W. Lee 1995. “How does foreign direct investment affect economic growth?” NBER working paper No. 5057.

Borensztein, E., J. Gregorio and J. W. Lee 1998. “How does foreign investment affect growth?” Journal of International Economics 45(1): 115-135.

Bowers, W. and G. Pierce 1975. “The illusion of deterrence in isaac ehrlich’s work on the deterrent effect of capital punishment” Yale Law Journal 85(2): 187-208.

Carrington, W. J.,  E. Detragiache and T. Vishwanath 1996. “Migration with endogenous moving costsAmerican Economic Review 86(4): 909-930.

Cameron, S. 1994. “A review of the econometric evidence on the effects of capital punishment” Journal of Socio-Economics 23(2): 197-214.

David, M. and H. Rapoport 2004 “Network effects and dynamics of migration and inequality: theory and evidence from MexicoBREAD Working Paper.

Ehrlich, I.1975. “The deterrent effect of capital punishment – a question of life and death” American Economic Review 65(3): 397-417.

Ehrlich, I. 1977. “The deterrent effect of capital punishment reply” American Economic Review 67(3):  452-58.

Ehrlich, I. 1996. “Crime, punishment and the market for offences” Journal of Economic Perspective 10(1): 43-67.

Engle, R. F. and C. W. J. Granger 1987. “Co-integration and error correction representation: estimation and testing” Econometrica 55(2): 251–276.

Gonzalez-Konig, G. and Q. Wodon 2005. “Remittances and inequality” Working Paper Series EC200506, World Bank.

Government of Pakistan, Economic Survey of Pakistan. (various issues).  Ministry of finance, Islamabad.

Handa, S. and D. King 1997. “Structural adjustment policies, income distribution and poverty: a review of the Jamaican experience” World Development 25(6): 915–30.

Haroon, J. 2005. “Does inequality matter for poverty reduction” SPDC’s Research Report 58.

International Monetary Fund, 2008. International Financial Statistics CD-ROM-2008. Washington, D.C. United States.

Johansen, S. 1991. “Estimation and hypothesis testing of co-integrating vectors in Gaussian vector autoregressive models” Econometrica 59(6): 1551–1580.

Johansen, S. 1995. Likelihood-Based Inference in Cointegrated Vector Autoregressive Models. Oxford University Press: Oxford.

Jones, R. C. 1998. “The renewed role of remittances in the New World Order” Economic Geography 74(1): 1-7.

Koechlin, V. and G. Leon  2006. “International remittances and income inequality: an empirical investigation international remittances and income inequality” Journal of Policy Reform 10(2): 228- 241.

Knowles, J.C. and R. Anker 1981. “An analysis of income transfers in developing country” Journal of Development Economics 8(3): 205-226.

Layson, S. 1983. “Homicide and deterrence: another view of the canadian time series evidence” Canadian Journal of Economics 16(3): 52-73.

Lerman, R. and S. Yitzhaki 1985. “Income inequality effects by income source: a new approach and application to the U.S.”  Review of Economics and Statistics 67 (2): 151-156.

Leones, J. P. and S. Feldman (1998). “Non-farm activity and rural household income: evidence from Philippine micro-data” Economic Development and Cultural Change 46(4): 789-806

Lucas, R. E. B. 1987. "Emigration to south Africa's mines" American Economic Review 77(3): 313-30.

Masih, A. M. M. and R. Masih 1996. “Energy consumption, real income and temporal causality” Energy Economics 18(3): 165-183.

Milanovic, B. 1987. “Remittances and income distribution” Journal of Economic Studies 14(5): 24-37.

Oberai, A. S. and H. K. M. Singh 1980. “Migration, remittances and rural development” International Labor Review 119(2): 229-241.

Peseran, M. H. and B. Peseran 1997. Working with Microfit 4.0: Interactive Econometric Analysis. Oxford University Press: Oxford.

Pesaran, M. H., Y. Shin and R. J. Smith 2001. “Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of level relationships” Journal of Applied Econometrics 16(3): 289–326.

Quibria,  M. G. 1997.  “International migration, remittances and income distribution in the source country: a synthesis” Bulletin of Economic Research 49 (1): 29-46.

Rodriguez, E. R. 1998. “International migration and income distribution in the PhilippinesEconomic Development and Cultural Change 46(2): 329–350.

Stark, O. 1978. “Economic-demographic interaction in the course of agricultural development: the case of rural-to-urban migration, RomeFood and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations.

Stark, O. and D. Levhari 1982. “On migration and risk in LDCs, economic development and cultural change” Journal of Development Economics 31(1): 191–196.

Stark, O., J. E. Taylor and S. Yitzhak 1986. “Remittances and inequality” Economic Journal 96(3): 722-740.

Stark, O., J. E. Taylor and S. Yitzhak 1988. “Migration, remittances and inequality: a sensitivity analysis using the extended Gini index” Journal of Development Economics 28(3): 309–22.

Stock, J. and M. Watson 1993. “A simple estimator of co-integrating vectors in higher order integrated systems” Econometrica 61(4): 783-820.

Taylor, J. E. and T. J. Wyatt 1996. “The shadow value of migrant remittances, income and inequality in a household-farm economy” Journal of Development Studies 32(6): 899-912.

Taylor, J. E. 1992. "Remittances and inequality reconsidered: direct, indirect and intertemporal effects" Journal of Policy Modeling 14(2): 187-208.

World Bank, 2008. World Development Indicators CD-ROM-2008. Washington, D.C. United States.

Yitzhaki, S. 1982. “On an extension of the Gini inequality index” International Economic Review 24(3): 617-628.



Appendix-A

Table 7: Estimated DOLS MODEL for Income Inequality

Dependent variable =LGINI
Variables
Coefficient
T-Statistic
Prob-value
Constant
2.356451
11.97780
0.0000
LREM
0.004635
8.267295
0.0000
LHDI
0.192813
3.645794
0.0013
LCPI
0.052890
8.083849
0.0000
LGS
0.022064
4.766731
0.0001
LGDPC
0.064113
14.66855
0.0000
DLGDP
-0.014576
-2.221755
0.0364
DLCPI (+1)
0.023289
2.256998
0.0338
DLGS
-0.011272
-2.594354
0.0162
DLHDI (+1)
0.194594
5.252829
0.0000
DLREM
-0.005885
-5.898395
0.0000
R2 = 0.999785                                             Adjusted R2 = 0.999692
S.E. of regression = 0.0018                         AIC = -9.576276
Durbin-Watson     = 1.792835                     F-statistic = 10714.32



[1] Remittance income refers to regular cash payments received from household members working outside the community for periods of 6 months or more (Leon and Feldman, 1998).
[2] Also Portes and Rumbaut (1990) and Lipton (1980)
[3] However, Stark and Yitzhaki, (1982) proposed a social welfare measure with desirable properties for assessing the effect of changes in income inequality and inequality upon social welfare.
[4] Lack of techniques fro properly assessing the contribution of out-migration to village income distribution, use of analytical frameworks which preclude unambiguous welfare judgments about changes in income distribution and lack of systematic empirical studies focusing on the appropriate income-earning entities are major reasons for opposing views regarding migration and the distribution of income in rural areas (Stark et al., 1986 and Stark et al., 1988)
[5] Remittances from internal migrants embody large returns to schooling component, and education is highly associated with household income in villages (Stark  et al.,, 1986).
[6] None of both these authors provide a formal model of the decision to migrate; they argue that impact of remittances on inequality depends on the stage of migration in the home country or location.
[7] Munshi (2003) explained that individuals with large networks are more likely to be employed and to hold higher paying jobs upon arrival in the U.S.A, which increases income inequality at their home place.
[8] Espinosa and Massey (1997) argued that social networks play a crucial role in mitigating the hazards of crossing the borders, with friends and relatives with previous migrant experience often accompanying new migrants across the border, showing them preferred routs and techniques of clandestine entry.
[9] The model in this study is static one that ignores number of dynamic economic consideration, especially those relating to saving and investment. It does consider the different uses of remittances.
[10] Urban families who have members who migrate are likely to occupy a lower position in the distribution of income within urban areas than their rural counterparts. That is, with similar level of income, migrants’ families will tend to be comparatively richer in rural areas (when compared to other rural households) and poorer in urban areas (when compared other urban households (Konig and Wodon, 2005, pp. 3).
[11] They used cross-country data of 78 economies utilizing ordinary least square, instrumental variables and panel data methods.
[12] Indeed, migration appears to increase inequality at low levels of society migration prevalence and reduces inequality at higher levels (David and Rapoport, 2004).
[13] In many developing economies migrants’ who send remittances to their families have vary little access to financial intermediaries: a small percentage have bank accounts, saving accounts or access to credits.
[14] This paper KPSS (Kwiatkowski, Philips, Schmidt, Shin, 1992) have been utilized to find the order of integration of variables in model.
[15] The estimates of Gini-Coefficient (proxy for Income Distribution) are available in the Economic Survey up to 1996-1997. After this a simple interpolation technique is applied to take the decline or growth in trend between two points in time and fill the data gapes between successive observations. However, a slightly more sophisticated method is applied to generate an interpolated series for inequality (Jamal, 2005).
[16] See for example, Easterly and Fisher (2001)
[17] Government current consumption expenditures for the purchase of goods and services including compensation of employees. It also includes most expenditure on national defense and security, but excludes government military expenditures that are part of government capital formation.
[18] Migration of population to cities as share of total population
[19] Private Credit captures the amount of credit channeled from savers, through financial intermediaries, to private firms. Private Credit is a comparatively comprehensive measure of credit issuing intermediaries since it also includes the credits of financial intermediaries that are not considered deposit money banks.
[20] see Jamal Haroon (2005)
[21] Theoretical form of KPSS test is based on Bahmani-Oskooee  2002, pp: 2497.
[22] In this study Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) and KPSS (Kwiatkowski, Philips, Schmidt, Shin, 1992) tests were applied.
[23] SBC is known as selecting the smallest lag length to specify a parsimonious model. The mean prediction error of AIC based model is 0.0005 while that of SBC based model is 0.0063 (Min B. Shrestha, 2003).
[24] Moreover, when the order of integration of the variable is known and if all the variables are I(1), the decision is made on the basis of upper bound. Similarly, if all the variables are I(0), then the decision is made on the basis of lower bound.

[25] LCPI is also stationary at level with trend and constant term
[26] At lower value of SBC, value of AIC is also low as shown in Table 2.
[27] For details see Easterly (2001)
[28] See Stark, Taylor and Yitzhaki, (1986)
[29] In financial development there is an interaction between remittances and financial institutions. First, providing financial intermediaries through remittances increase benefits to senders and recipients because it improves opportunities to save, borrow, buy other financial services like insurance, invest, and helps financial institutions to mobiles in local part of society where money is located. Due to international migration, increases in households’ assets have national affects on growth and development in the economy. Thus national savings and investment ratio can improve growth rate when foreign saving are allocated to productive projects to strengthen productive base of local economy in the development process.
[30] Indeed, he has argued that testing the significance of CEt-1, which is supposed to carry a negative coefficient, is relatively more efficient way of establishing Co-integration.